home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- /*We continue with the dissenting opinions in the Omni case. */
- Justice Stevens, with whom Justice White and Justice Marshall
- join, dissenting.
-
- Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides in part: "Every contract,
- combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in
- restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with
- foreign nations, is declared to be illegal." 15 U. S. C. MDRV 1
- (emphasis added). Although we have previously recognized that a
- completely literal interpretation of the word "every" cannot have
- been intended by Congress, {1} the Court today carries this
- recognition to an extreme by deciding that agreements between
- municipalities, or their officials, and private parties to use
- the zoning power to confer exclusive privileges in a particular
- line of commerce are beyond the reach of MDRV 1. History,
- tradition, and the facts of this case all demonstrate that the
- Court's attempt to create a "better" and less inclusive Sherman
- Act, cf. West Virginia University Hospitals, Inc. v. Casey, ---
- U. S. --- (1991) (slip op., at 17) is ill advised.
-
- I
-
- As a preface to a consideration of the "state action" and
- socalled "Noerr-Pennington" exemptions to the Sherman Act, it is
- appropriate to remind the Court that one of the classic common-
- law examples of a prohibited contract in restraint of trade
- involved an agreement between a public official and a private
- party. The public official -- the Queen of England -- had
- granted one of her subjects a monopoly in the making,
- importation, and sale of playing cards in order to generate
- revenues for the crown. A competitor challenged the grant in The
- Case of Monopolies, 11 Co. Rep. 84, 77 Eng. Rep. 1260 (Q.B.
- 1602), and prevailed. Chief Justice Popham explained on behalf
- of the bench:
-
- "The Queen was . . . deceived in her grant; for the
- Queen . . . intended it to be for the weal public, and it
- will be employed for the private gain of the patentee, and
- for the prejudice of the weal public; moreover the Queen
- meant that the abuse should be taken away, which shall never
- be by this patent, but potius the abuse will be increased
- for the private benefit of the patentee, and therefore . . .
- this grant is void jure Regio." Id., at 87a; 77 Eng. Rep.,
- at 1264.
-
- In the case before us today, respondent alleges that the city of
- Columbia, South Carolina, has entered into a comparable agreement
- to give respondent a monopoly in the sale of billboard
- advertising. After a three-week trial, a jury composed of
- citizens of the vicinage found that, despite the city fathers'
- denials, there was indeed such an agreement, presumably motivated
- in part by past favors in the form of political advertising, in
- part by friendship, and in part by the expectation of a
- beneficial future relationship -- and in any case, not
- exclusively by a concern for the general public interest. {2}
-
- Today the Court acknowledges the anticompetitive consequences of
- this and similar agreements but decides that they should be
- exempted from the coverage of the Sherman Act because it fears
- that enunciating a rule that allows the motivations of public
- officials to be probed may mean that innocent municipal officials
- may be harassed with baseless charges. The holding evidences an
- unfortunate lack of confidence in our judicial system and will
- foster the evils the Sherman Act was designed to eradicate.
-
- /* The idea being that a jury and then Judge behind that can
- divine between the cases in which there is a form of "bribery"
- and where there is just a decision between competing public
- policy concerns. */
-
- II
-
- There is a distinction between economic regulation, on the one
- hand, and regulation designed to protect the public health,
- safety, and environment. In antitrust parlance a "regulated
- industry" is one in which decisions about prices and output are
- made not by individual firms, but rather by a public body or a
- collective process subject to governmental approval. Economic
- regulation of the motor carrier and airline industries was
- imposed by the Federal Government in the 1930s; the
- "deregulation" of those industries did not eliminate all the
- other types of regulation that continue to protect our safety and
- environmental concerns.
-
- The antitrust laws reflect a basic national policy favoring free
- markets over regulated markets. {3} In essence, the Sherman Act
- prohibits private unsupervised regulation of the prices and
- output of goods in the marketplace. That prohibition is
- inapplicable to specific industries which Congress has exempted
- from the antitrust laws and subjected to regulatory supervision
- over price and output decisions. Moreover, the so-called "state
- action" exemption from the Sherman Act reflects the Court's
- understanding that Congress did not intend the statute to preempt
- a State's economic regulation of commerce within its own borders.
-
- The contours of the state action exemption are relatively well-
- defined in our cases. Ever since our decision in Olsen v. Smith,
- 195 U. S. 332 (1904), which upheld a Texas statute fixing the
- rates charged by pilots operating in the Port of Galveston, it
- has been clear that a State's decision to displace competition
- with economic regulation is not prohibited by the Sherman Act.
- Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943), the case most frequently
- identified with the state action exemption, involved a decision
- by California to substitute sales quotas and price control -- the
- purest form of economic regulation -- for competition in the
- market for California raisins.
-
- In Olsen, the State itself had made the relevant pricing
- decision. In Parker, the regulation of the marketing of
- California's 1940 crop of raisins was administered by state
- officials. Thus, when a state agency, or the State itself,
- engages in economic regulation, the Sherman Act is inapplicable.
- Hoover v. Ronwin, 466 U. S. 558, 568-569 (1984); Bates v. State
- Bar of Arizona, 433 U. S. 350, 360 (1977).
-
- Underlying the Court's recognition of this state action exemption
- has been respect for the fundamental principle of federalism. As
- we stated in Parker, 317 U. S., at 351, "In a dual system of
- government in which, under the Constitution, the states are
- sovereign, save only as Congress may constitutionally subtract
- from their authority, an unexpressed purpose to nullify a state's
- control over its officers and agents is not lightly to be
- attributed to Congress."
-
- However, this Court recognized long ago that the deference due
- States within our federal system does not extend fully to conduct
- undertaken by municipalities. Rather, all sovereign authority
- "within the geographical limits of the United States" resides
- with "the Government of the United States, or [with] the States
- of the Union. There exist within the broad domain of sovereignty
- but these two. There may be cities, counties, and other
- organized bodies with limited legislative functions, but they are
- all derived from, or exist in, subordination to one or the other
- of these." United States v. Kagama, 118 U. S. 375, 379 (1886).
-
- Unlike States, municipalities do not constitute bedrocks within
- our system of federalism. And also unlike States, municipalities
- are more apt to promote their narrow parochial interests "without
- regard to extraterritorial impact and regional efficiency."
- Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U. S. 389, 404
- (1978); see also The Federalist No. 10 (J. Madison) (describing
- the greater tendency of smaller societies to promote oppressive
- and narrow interests above the common good). "If municipalities
- were free to make economic choices counseled solely by their own
- parochial interests and without regard to their anticompetitive
- effects, a serious chink in the armor of antitrust protection
- would be introduced at odds with the comprehensive national
- policy Congress established." Lafayette v. Louisiana Power &
- Light Co., 435 U. S., at 408. Indeed, "[i]n light of the serious
- economic dislocation which could result if cities were free to
- place their own parochial interests above the Nation's economic
- goals reflected in the antitrust laws, . . . we are especially
- unwilling to presume that Congress intended to exclude
- anticompetitive municipal action from their reach." Id., at 412-
- 413. {4}
-
- /* Which is a quotation directly contrary to the majority's
- point. The jury and court found that the cities action were not
- even legal under South Carolina law, therefore, the preservation
- of STATE rights is not advanced by the majority opinion. */
-
- Nevertheless, insofar as municipalities may serve to implement
- state policies, we have held that economic regulation
- administered by a municipality may also be exempt from Sherman
- Act coverage if it is enacted pursuant to a clearly articulated
- and affirmatively expressed state directive "to replace
- competition with regulation." Hoover, 466 U. S., at 569.
- However, the mere fact that a municipality acts within its
- delegated authority is not sufficient to exclude its
- anticompetitive behavior from the reach of the Sherman Act.
- "Acceptance of such a proposition -- that the general grant of
- power to enact ordinances necessarily implies state authorization
- to enact specific anticompetitive ordinances -- would wholly
- eviscerate the concepts of `clear articulation and affirmative
- expression' that our precedents require." Community
- Communications Co. v. Boulder, 455 U.S. 40, 56 (1982).
-
- Accordingly, we have held that the critical decision to
- substitute economic regulation for competition is one that must
- be made by the State. That decision must be articulated with
- sufficient clarity to identify the industry in which the State
- intends that economic regulation shall replace competition. The
- terse statement of the reason why the municipality's actions in
- Hallie v. Eau Claire, 471 U. S. 34 (1985), was exempt from the
- Sherman Act illustrates the point: "They were taken pursuant to a
- clearly articulated state policy to replace competition in the
- provision of sewage services with regulation." Id., at 47. {5}
-
- III
-
- Today the Court adopts a significant enlargement of the state
- action exemption. The South Carolina statutes that confer zoning
- authority on municipalities in the State do not articulate any
- state policy to displace competition with economic regulation in
- any line of commerce or in any specific industry. As the Court
- notes, the state statutes were expressly adopted to promote the
- "`health, safety, morals or the general welfare of the
- community,'" see ante, at 4-5, n. 3. Like Colorado's grant of
- "home rule" powers to the city of Boulder, they are simply
- neutral on the question whether the municipality should displace
- competition with economic regulation in any industry. There is
- not even an arguable basis for concluding that the State
- authorized the city of Columbia to enter into exclusive
- agreements with any person, or to use the zoning power to protect
- favored citizens from competition. {6} Nevertheless, under the
- guise of acting pursuant to a state legislative grant to regulate
- health, safety, and welfare, the city of Columbia in this case
- enacted an ordinance that amounted to economic regulation of the
- billboard market; as the Court recognizes, the ordinance
- "obviously benefited COA, which already had its billboards in
- place . . . [and] severely hindered Omni's ability to compete."
- Ante, at 2.
-
- Concededly, it is often difficult to differentiate economic
- regulation from municipal regulation of health, safety, and
- welfare. "Social and safety regulation have economic impacts,
- and economic regulation has social and safety effects." D.
- Hjelmfelt, Antitrust and Regulated Industries 3 (1985). It is
- nevertheless important to determine when purported general
- welfare regulation in fact constitutes economic regulation by its
- purpose and effect of displacing competition. "An example of
- economic regulation which is disguised by another stated purpose
- is the limitation of advertising by lawyers for the stated
- purpose of protecting the public from incompetent lawyers. Also,
- economic regulation posing as safety regulation is often
- encountered in the health care industry." Id., at 3-4.
-
- In this case, the jury found that the city's ordinance --
- ostensibly one promoting health, safety, and welfare -- was in
- fact enacted pursuant to an agreement between city officials and
- a private party to restrict competition. In my opinion such a
- finding necessarily leads to the conclusion that the city's
- ordinance was fundamentally a form of economic regulation of the
- billboard market rather than a general welfare regulation having
- incidental anticompetitive effects. Because I believe our cases
- have wisely held that the decision to embark upon economic
- regulation is a nondelegable one that must expressly be made by
- the State in the context of a specific industry in order to
- qualify for state action immunity, see, e. g., Olsen v. Smith,
- 195 U. S. 332 (1904) (Texas pilotage statutes expressly regulated
- both entry and rates in the Port of Galveston); Parker v. Brown,
- 317 U. S. 341 (1943) (California statute expressly authorized the
- raisin market regulatory program), I would hold that the city of
- Columbia's economic regulation of the billboard market pursuant
- to a general state grant of zoning power is not exempt from
- antitrust scrutiny. {7}
-
- Underlying the Court's reluctance to find the city of Columbia's
- enactment of the billboard ordinance pursuant to a private
- agreement to constitute unauthorized economic regulation is the
- Court's fear that subjecting the motivations and effects of
- municipal action to antitrust scrutiny will result in public
- decisionmaking being "made subject to ex post facto judicial
- assessment of `the public interest.' " Ante, at 11. That fear,
- in turn, rests on the assumption that "it is both inevitable and
- desirable that public officials often agree to do what one or
- another group of private citizens urges upon them." Ante, at 9.
-
- The Court's assumption that an agreement between private parties
- and public officials is an "inevitable" precondition for official
- action, however, is simply wrong. {8} Indeed, I am persuaded that
- such agreements are the exception rather than the rule, and that
- they are, and should be, disfavored. The mere fact that an
- official body adopts a position that is advocated by a private
- lobbyist is plainly not sufficient to establish an agreement to
- do so. See Fisher v. Berkeley, 475 U. S. 260, 266-267 (1986);
- cf. Theatre Enterprises, Inc. v. Paramount Film Distributing
- Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 541 (1954). Nevertheless, in many
- circumstances, it would seem reasonable to infer -- as the jury
- did in this case -- that the official action is the product of an
- agreement intended to elevate particular private interests over
- the general good.
-
- In this case, the city took two separate actions that protected
- the local monopolist from threatened competition. It first
- declared a moratorium on any new billboard construction, despite
- the city attorney's advice that the city had no power to do so.
- When the moratorium was invalidated in state court litigation, it
- was replaced with an apparently valid ordinance that clearly had
- the effect of creating formidable barriers to entry in the
- billboard market. Throughout the city's decisionmaking process
- in enacting the various ordinances, undisputed evidence
- demonstrated that Columbia Outdoor Advertising had met with city
- officials privately as well as publicly. As the Court of Appeals
- noted: "Implicit in the jury verdict was a finding that the city
- was not acting pursuant to the direction or purposes of the South
- Carolina statutes but conspired solely to further COA's
- commercial purposes to the detriment of competition in the
- billboard industry." 891 F. 2d 1127, 1133 (CA4 1989).
-
- Judges who are closer to the trial process than we are do not
- share the Court's fear that juries are not capable of recognizing
- the difference between independent municipal action and action
- taken for the sole purpose of carrying out an anticompetitive
- agreement for the private party. {9} See, e. g., In re Japanese
- Electronic Products Antitrust Litigation, 631 F. 2d 1069, 1079
- (CA3 1980) ("The law presumes that a jury will find facts and
- reach a verdict by rational means. It does not contemplate
- scientific precision but does contemplate a resolution of each
- issue on the basis of a fair and reasonable assessment of the
- evidence and a fair and reasonable application of the relevant
- legal rules"). Indeed, the problems inherent in determining
- whether the actions of municipal officials are the product of an
- illegal agreement are substantially the same as those arising in
- cases in which the actions of business executives are subjected
- to antitrust scrutiny. {10}
-
- The difficulty of proving whether an agreement motivated a course
- of conduct should not in itself intimidate this Court into
- exempting those illegal agreements that are proven by convincing
- evidence. Rather, the Court should, if it must, attempt to deal
- with these problems of proof as it has in the past -- through
- heightened evidentiary standards rather than through judicial
- expansion of exemptions from the Sherman Act. See, e. g.,
- Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.
- S. 574 (1986) (allowing summary judgment where evidence of a
- predatory pricing conspiracy in violation of the Sherman Act was
- founded largely upon circumstantial evidence); Monsanto Co. v.
- Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 768 (1984) (holding that
- a plaintiff in a vertical price-fixing case must produce evidence
- which "tends to exclude the possibility of independent action").
-
- Unfortunately, the Court's decision today converts what should be
- nothing more than an anticompetitive agreement undertaken by a
- municipality that enjoys no special status in our federalist
- system into a lawful exercise of public decisionmaking. Although
- the Court correctly applies principles of federalism in refusing
- to find a "conspiracy exception" to the Parker state action
- doctrine when a State acts in a nonproprietary capacity, it errs
- in extending the state action exemption to municipalities that
- enter into private anticompetitive agreements under the guise of
- acting pursuant to a general state grant of authority to regulate
- health, safety, and welfare. Unlike the previous limitations
- this Court has imposed on Congress' sweeping mandate in MDRV 1,
- which found support in our common-law traditions or our system of
- federalism, see n. 1, supra, the Court's wholesale exemption of
- municipal action from antitrust scrutiny amounts to little more
- than a bold and disturbing act of judicial legislation which
- dramatically curtails the statutory prohibition against "every"
- contract in restraint of trade. {11}
-
- IV
-
- Just as I am convinced that municipal "lawmaking that has been
- infected by selfishly motivated agreement with private
- interests," ante, at 17, is not authorized by a grant of zoning
- authority, and therefore not within the state action exemption,
- so am I persuaded that a private party's agreement with selfishly
- motivated public officials is sufficient to remove the antitrust
- immunity that protects private lobbying under Eastern Railroad
- Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127
- (1961), and Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U. S. 657 (1965).
- Although I agree that the "sham" exception to the Noerr-
- Pennington rule exempting lobbying activities from the antitrust
- laws does not apply to the private petitioner's conduct in this
- case for the reasons stated by the Court in Part III of its
- opinion, I am satisfied that the evidence in the record is
- sufficient to support the jury's finding that a conspiracy
- existed between the private party and the municipal officials in
- this case so as to remove the private petitioner's conduct from
- the scope of NoerrPennington antitrust immunity. Accordingly, I
- would affirm the judgment of the Court of Appeals as to both the
- city of Columbia and Columbia Outdoor Advertising.
-
- I respectfully dissent.
-
-
- ----------------------------------------------------------------
- Note 1:
-
- Construing the statute in the light of the common law concerning
- contracts in restraint of trade, we have concluded that only
- unreasonable restraints are prohibited.
-
- "One problem presented by the language of MDRV 1 of the Sherman
- Act is that it cannot mean what it says. The statute says that
- `every' contract that restrains trade is unlawful. But, as Mr.
- Justice Brandeis perceptively noted, restraint is the very
- essence of every contract; read literally, MDRV 1 would outlaw
- the entire body of private contract law. Yet it is that body of
- law that establishes the enforceability of commercial agreements
- and enables competitive markets -- indeed, a competitive economy
- -- to function effectively.
-
- "Congress, however, did not intend the text of the Sherman Act to
- delineate the full meaning of the statute or its application in
- concrete situations. The legislative history makes it perfectly
- clear that it expected the courts to give shape to the statute's
- broad mandate by drawing on common-law tradition. The Rule of
- Reason, with its origins in common-law precedents long antedating
- the Sherman Act, has served that purpose. . . . [The Rule of
- Reason] focuses directly on the challenged restraint's impact on
- competitive conditions." National Society of Professional
- Engineers v. United States, 435 U. S. 679, 687-688 (1978)
- (footnotes omitted).
-
- We have also confined the Sherman Act's mandate by holding that
- the independent actions of the sovereign States and their
- officials are not covered by the language of the Act. Parker v.
- Brown, 317 U. S. 341 (1943).
-
- Note 2:
-
- The jury returned its verdict pursuant to the following
- instructions given by the District Court:
-
- "So if by the evidence you find that that person involved in this
- case procured and brought about the passage of ordinances solely
- for the purpose of hindering, delaying or otherwise interfering
- with the access of the Plaintiff to the marketing area involved
- in this case . . . and thereby conspired, then, of course, their
- conduct would not be excused under the antitrust laws.
-
- "So once again an entity may engage in . . . legitimate
- lobbying . . . to procure legislati[on] even if the motive
- behind the lobbying is anti competitive.
-
- "If you find Defendants conspired together with the intent to
- foreclose the Plaintiff from meaningful access to a legitimate
- decision making process with regard to the ordinances in
- question, then your verdict would be for the Plaintiff on that
- issue." App. 81.
-
- Note 3:
-
- "The Sherman Act reflects a legislative judgment that ultimately
- competition will produce not only lower prices, but also better
- goods and services. `The heart of our national economic policy
- long has been faith in the value of competition.' Standard Oil
- Co. v. FTC, 340 U. S. 231, 248. The assumption that competition
- is the best method of allocating resources in a free market
- recognizes that all elements of a bargain -- quality, service,
- safety, and durability -- and not just the immediate cost, are
- favorably affected by the free opportunity to select among
- alternative offers. Even assuming occasional exceptions to the
- presumed consequences of competition, the statutory policy
- precludes inquiry into the question whether competition is good
- or bad." National Society of Professional Engineers, 435 U. S.,
- at 695.
-
- Note 4:
-
- In Owen v. City of Independence, 445 U. S. 622 (1980), this Court
- recognized that "notwithstanding [42 U. S. C.] MDRV 1983's
- expansive language and absence of any express incorporation of
- common-law immunities, we have, on several occasions, found that
- a tradition of immunity was so firmly rooted in the common law
- and was supported by such strong policy reasons that `Congress
- would have specifically so provided had it wished to abolish the
- doctrine.' Pierson v. Ray, 386 U. S. 547, 555 (1967)." Id., at
- 637. Nevertheless, the Court refused to find a firmly
- established immunity enjoyed by municipal corporations at common
- law for the torts of their agents. "Where the immunity claimed
- by the defendant was well established at common law at the time
- [42 U. S. C.] MDRV 1983 was enacted, and where its rationale was
- compatible with the purposes of the Civil Rights Act, we have
- construed the statute to incorporate that immunity. But there is
- no tradition of immunity for municipal corporations, and neither
- history nor policy supports a construction of MDRV 1983 that
- would justify" according them such immunity. Id., at 638. See
- also Will v. Michigan Dept. of State Police, 491 U. S. 58, 70
- (1989) ("States are protected by the Eleventh Amendment while
- municipalities are not . . .").
-
- Note 5:
-
- Contrary to the Court's reading of Hallie, our opinion in that
- case emphasized the industry-specific character of the Wisconsin
- legislation in explaining why the delegation satisfied the `clear
- articulation' requirement. At issue in Hallie was the town's
- independent decision to refuse to provide sewage treatment
- services to nearby towns -- a decision that had been expressly
- authorized by the Wisconsin legislation. 471 U. S., at 41. We
- wrote:
-
- "Applying the analysis of Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light
- Co., 435 U.S. 389 (1978), it is sufficient that the statutes
- authorized the City to provide sewage services and also to
- determine the areas to be served." Id., at 42.
-
- "Nor do we agree with the Towns' contention that the statutes at
- issue here are neutral on state policy. The Towns' attempt to
- liken the Wisconsin statutes to the Home Rule Amendment involved
- in Boulder, arguing that the Wisconsin statutes are neutral
- because they leave the City free to pursue either anticompetitive
- conduct or free-market competition in the field of sewage
- services. The analogy to the Home Rule Amendment involved in
- Boulder is inapposite. That Amendment to the Colorado
- Constitution allocated only the most general authority to
- municipalities to govern local affairs. We held that it was
- neutral and did not satisfy the `clear articulation' component of
- the state action test. The Amendment simply did not address the
- regulation of cable television. Under home rule the municipality
- was to be free to decide every aspect of policy relating to cable
- television, as well as policy relating to any other field of
- regulation of local concern. Here, in contrast, the State has
- specifically authorized Wisconsin cities to provide sewage
- services and has delegated to the cities the express authority to
- take action that foreseeably will result in anticompetitive
- effects. No reasonable argument can be made that these statutes
- are neutral in the same way that Colorado's Home Rule Amendment
- was." Id., at 43.
-
- We rejected the argument that the delegation was insufficient
- because it did not expressly mention the foreseeable
- anticompetitive consequences of the city of Eau Claire's conduct,
- but we surely did not hold that the mere fact that incidental
- anticompetitive consequences are foreseeable is sufficient to
- immunize otherwise unauthorized restrictive agreements between
- cities and private parties.
-
- Note 6:
-
- The authority to regulate the " `location, height, bulk, number
- of stories and size of buildings and other structures,' " see
- ante, at 5, n. 3 (citation omitted), may of course have an
- indirect effect on the total output in the billboard industry,
- see ante, at 7, n. 4, as well as on a number of other industries,
- but the Court surely misreads our cases when it implies that a
- general grant of zoning power represents a clearly articulated
- decision to authorize municipalities to enter into agreements to
- displace competition in every industry that is affected by zoning
- regulation.
-
- Note 7:
-
- A number of Courts of Appeals have held that a municipality which
- exercises its zoning power to further a private agreement to
- restrain trade is not entitled to state action immunity. See, e.
- g., Westborough Mall, Inc. v. Cape Girardeau, 693 F. 2d 733, 746
- (CA8 1982) ("Even if zoning in general can be characterized as
- `state action,' . . . a conspiracy to thwart normal zoning
- procedures and to directly injure the plaintiffs by illegally
- depriving them of their property is not in furtherance of any
- clearly articulated state policy"); Whitworth v. Perkins, 559 F.
- 2d 378, 379 (CA5 1977) ("The mere presence of the zoning
- ordinance does not necessarily insulate the defendants from
- antitrust liability where, as here, the plaintiff asserts that
- the enactment of the ordinance was itself a part of the alleged
- conspiracy to restrain trade").
-
- Note 8:
-
- No such agreement was involved in Hallie v. Eau Claire, 471 U. S.
- 34 (1985). In that case the plaintiffs challenged independent
- action -- the determination of the service area of the city's
- sewage system -- that had been expressly authorized by Wisconsin
- legislation. The absence of any such agreement provided the
- basis for our decision in Fisher v. Berkeley, 475 U. S. 260, 266-
- 267 (1986) ("[t]he distinction between unilateral and concerted
- action is critical here . . . [t]hus, if the Berkeley Ordinance
- stabilizes rents without this element of concerted action, the
- program it establishes cannot run afoul of MDRV 1").
-
- Note 9:
-
- The instructions in this case, fairly read, told the jury that
- the plaintiff should not prevail unless the ordinance was enacted
- for the sole purpose of interfering with access to the market.
- See supra, at 3, n. 2. Thus, this case is an example of one of
- the "polar extremes," see ante, at 9, n. 5, that juries -- as
- well as Solomon -- can readily identify. The mixed motive cases
- that concern the Court should present no problem if juries are
- given instructions comparable to those given below. When the
- Court describes my position as assuming that municipal action
- that was not prompted "exclusively by a concern for the general
- public interest" is enough to create antitrust liability, ibid.,
- it simply ignores the requirement that the plaintiff must prove
- that the municipal action is the product of an anticompetitive
- agreement with private parties. Contrary to our square holding
- in Fisher v. Berkeley, 475 U. S. 260 (1986), today the Court
- seems to assume that municipal action which is not entirely
- immune from antitrust scrutiny will automatically violate the
- antitrust laws.
-
- Note 10:
-
- "There are many obstacles to discovering conspiracies, but the
- most frequent difficulties are three. First, price-fixers and
- similar miscreants seldom admit their conspiracy or agree in the
- open. Often, we can infer the agreement only from their
- behavior. Second, behavior can sometimes be coordinated without
- any communication or other observable and reprehensible behavior.
- Third, the causal connection between an observable, controllable
- act -- such as a solicitation or meeting -- and subsequent
- parallel action may be obscure." 6 P. Areeda, Antitrust Law MDRV
- 1400, at 3-4 (1986).
-
- See also Turner, The Definition of Agreement under the Sherman
- Act: Conscious Parallelism and Refusals to Deal, 75 Harv. L.
- Rev. 655 (1962) (discussing difficulties of condemning parallel
- anticompetitive action absent explicit agreement among the
- parties).
-
- Note 11:
-
- As the Court previously has noted:
-
- "In 1972, there were 62,437 different units of local government
- in this country. Of this number 23,885 were special districts
- which had a defined goal or goals for the provision of one or
- several services, while the remaining 38,552 represented the
- number of counties, municipalities, and townships, most of which
- have broad authority for general governance subject to
- limitations in one way or another imposed by the State. These
- units may, and do, participate in and affect the economic life of
- this Nation in a great number and variety of ways. When these
- bodies act as owners and providers of services, they are fully
- capable of aggrandizing other economic units with which they
- interrelate, with the potential of serious distortion of the
- rational and efficient allocation of resources, and the
- efficiency of free markets which the regime of competition
- embodied in the antitrust laws is thought to engender." Lafayette
- v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U. S. 389, 407-408 (1978)
- (footnotes omitted).
-